Disclaimer: This is an example of a student written essay.
Click here for sample essays written by our professional writers.

Any information contained within this essay is intended for educational purposes only. It should not be treated as authoritative or accurate when considering investments or other financial products.

Comparative Institutional Advantage As A Determinant Of Fdi Economics Essay

Paper Type: Free Essay Subject: Economics
Wordcount: 5396 words Published: 1st Jan 2015

Reference this

The Varieties of Capitalism literature proposes a concept of institutional arbitrage: as a result of comparative institutional advantages due to different investment incentives provided by types of institutions, companies relocate activities to countries, where the institutional set-up best supports a given activity. We test this proposition using German outward FDI figures on a sectoral level. We find evidence of institutional arbitrage using different ways to operationalize system differences between countries. Evidence crucially depend on the size of the receiving sector. FDI in a sector with comparative institutional advantage increases with sector size, while for a sector without a comparative institutional advantage the size of the sector does not matter.

1. Introduction

The comparative capitalism literature around Hall and Soskice’s (2001) Varieties of Capitalism puts forward a strong claim of comparative institutional advantage.The institutional set-ups in coordinated (CME) and liberal market economies (LME) are said to provide firms with comparative advantages in specific industries, in which dominating research patterns are more prominently utilized than others. Specifically, in LMEs institutions facilitate radical innovations and hence, firms have a comparative advantage in the very industries, which require radical innovation to prosper. On the other end of the spectrum, CMEs exhibit institutional features, which give the opportunity to engage in more incremental innovation strategies, which are utilized more in some industries than in others. The literature provides a considerable number of empirical investigations into the existence and the extent of comparative institutional advantage. The overall picture is mixed, but taking everything into consideration there seems to be considerable evidence in favor of comparative advantage of nations.

Get Help With Your Essay

If you need assistance with writing your essay, our professional essay writing service is here to help!

Essay Writing Service

A further logical step for Hall and Soskice (2001) is then to propose a concept of institutional arbitrage: firms should exploit existing comparative institutional advantages by shifting production to countries, where the institutional set-up is best for the activity. Decreasing barriers to the flow of production factors and goods due to “globalization” make it easier to shift production to other countries. Apart from “traditional” determinants of foreign direct investment such as differences in labor cost, market size, transport costs and generally the distance between countries, the concept of institutional arbitrage implies an institutional motive for locational production choices of companies.

The empirical literature on the new institutional economics has long introduced institutional variables in order to explain foreign direct investment and trade patterns. The focus there, however, is on the quality of institutions in the colloquial sense of the word meaning “good” institutions. For instance, it can be shown that lower corruption in countries correlates with higher FDI inflows; similarly, the quality of contract enforcement in countries can explain parts of the production pattern of countries. This resonates with the large Doing Business project led by the World Bank (2007),which collects worldwide data on institutional differences in a wide range of areas. These data are then utilized to show the impact of institutional quality on financial development and growth.

The comparative capitalism literature has a different focus: different types of institutions exist as a result of multiple equilibria with complementary institutions. As stated above, the focus here is on the different investment incentives provided by different varieties of institutions. Hence, simply put, institutions in advanced capitalist countries are not better or worse, but lead to different outcomes with respect to industrial structures and dynamics or distribution of income. While it can be shown that institutional differences in kind lead to different sectoral growth rates and investment strategies (Carlin and Meyer 2003),the impact on cross-country investment and thereby the existence of institutional arbitrage has not been tested empirically, yet, on a cross-sectoral level. We make a first step of doing so using data of German outward foreign direct investment (FDI) on a sectoral breakdown. We follow the gravity equations approach, which explains cross-country variation of FDI flows on the basis of market size, labor costs and distance between host country and the country of origin. In order to model the institutional set-up of the host-country we include a number of institutional variables ranging from a simple binary system variable showing whether a host country is classified as CME or LME to indicators for specific institutional sub-systems of the host countries. Hence, the basic measure says whether countries are liberal market economies or coordinated market economies. This is amended by continuous measures of degrees of coordination using an indicator developed by Knell and Srholec (2007)and an expanded and updated version of the coordination index proposed by Hall and Gingerich (2004).In addition, we include indicators of industrial relations, corporate governance and labour laws. In a similar fashion as Allen et al. (2006),we group industrial sectors according to the dominant innovation pattern.

Our analysis suggests that there is a systematic institutional arbitrage to be observed by German companies. In other words, German companies contemplating relocation do seem to be influenced by the institutional endowment of host countries. However, this effect depends on the size of the receiving sector: larger sectors receive more German FDI if they exhibit a comparative advantage. If the advantage is not present, the size does not matter.

The analysis proceeds as follows: chapter 2 sets the stage by incorporating the concept of comparative institutional advantage of the comparative capitalism literature into its usage within the broader stream of new institutional economics. Against this backdrop, we then discuss the concept of institutional arbitrage as advocated by Hall and Soskice and give an overview about the empirical determinants of FDI. Chapter 3 presents our methodology, which follows widely used empirical methods of international economics to model direction of investment; chapter 4 presents the data. The results of our data are presented in chapter 5, while chapter 6 concludes

2. Comparative institutional advantage and foreign direct investment

Comparative advantage refers to lower opportunity cost of production in certain goods and services. In different strands of trade theory, comparative advantage based on labour productivity (Ricardo) and relative factor abundance (Heckscher/Ohlin), explains specialization and the direction of trade. Simply put, firms specialize in industries, for which in their respective countries the opportunity costs of producing are lowest and export those goods. Introducing institutions into the concept of comparative advantage of nations gives rise to the notion of comparative institutional advantage. It states that institutions (North 1990)provide companies in a given country with comparative advantages in the production of specific goods and services (Hall and Soskice 2001, Belloc 2006).For our purposes it is less relevant, whether countries have comparative or absolute advantages from the institutional environment. What is more, empirically observing trade or investment patterns of countries allows to infer a comparative advantage and not an absolute advantage (see also discussion in Franzese and Mosher 2002).

The theoretical and empirical literature on comparative institutional advantage can be broadly classified along two lines. On the one hand, some authors attempt to show that a higher quality of institutions in one country provides firms with a better contracting environment relatively to firms in a country with lower quality of institutions. This then has an effect on the whole economy. The second line of research, to which the present paper attempts to make a contribution, puts the main emphasis on different types of contracting institutions, which create different institutional environments entailing sectoral comparative advantages.

Including quality differences of institutions in theoretical and empirical studies to explain growth and development differentials around the world has substantially advanced growth theories. It has been shown that the quality of institutions, in particular of contracting institutions, has a long-term impact on the development of countries (Acemoglu et al. 2001, Acemoglu and Johnson 2005, North 1990).Also, trade theory is increasingly incorporating institutions and differences in contract enforcement as a way to reconcile theoretical predictions with actually observed trade patterns (Belloc 2006).

The theoretical background is provided by institutional economics approaches such as property rights theory (Hart 1995, Hart and Moore 1990) and transaction cost economics (Williamson 1985, 2000). There, the unifying feature is the importance of relation-specific investments for the choice of specific types of contractual arrangements. Property rights literature emphasizes the crucial role of residual control rights in an enterprise. Since contracts are incomplete, it is the owner who decides over the distribution of total surplus in cases of ambiguities or imprecision. Hence, there will always be under-investment of the non-owner as compared to a first-best solution. Low quality of contract enforcement in a country aggravates this because under-investment in relation-specific assets of non-owners will be even greater. Ceteris paribus, it is argued that the better the contract enforcement in a country, the more relation-specific investments are undertaken. As a consequence, countries with better contract enforcement (for instance less corruption in the judiciary) enjoy a comparative institutional advantage in those economic activities, which heavily rely on relation-specific investments. Oxley (1999) makes a related observation in a transaction cost economics framework: the quality of intellectual property rights protection in a host country has an influence on the governance choice by the foreign investor: the weaker the protection the more hierarchical the chosen governance structure.

Recently, a rapidly growing literature has used trade data to investigate whether trade flows follow the theoretically predicted lines of comparative institutional advantage. All of them use similar indicators to capture the differential need for contracting institutions, such as the contract intensity of industries as proxied by the thickness of input product markets (Nunn 2007),the complexity of products in industries measured by the concentration of input goods (Levchenko 2007)or survey results about the complexity of tasks in a given industry (Costinot 2009).They find that countries with better contracting institutions export relatively more of contract-intensive products than countries with worse institutions.

Differences in the quality of financial systems can also impact on comparative advantages of countries otherwise equally endowed (Baldwin 1989, Bardhan and Kletzer 1987).Earlier theoretical contributions are more broadly echoed in the Law and Finance literature (see an overview by Beck and Levine 2005 and La Porta et al. 2008). Empirical investigations that explicitly model comparative advantages arising of better (or worse) financial systems confirm this (e.g. Svaleryd and Vlachos 2005).

Including quality measures of institutions in theoretical and empirical papers in a wide range of economic applications is commonplace. Less attention has been paid to different types of institutions, such as different degrees of non-market coordination. This will be discussed in the following section.

2.1 Type of institutions: Varieties of Capitalism

Contributors in this tradition emphasize the point that institutions of coordination can protect relation-specific investments and thereby lower the degree of under-investment. That is, given equally good contract enforcement characteristics, different institutional settings result in incentives to invest in relation-specific investments. Hence, national institutions affect the production capacity differently across sectors of the economy.

Tightly coupled with this is the notion of institutional complementarities: simply put, two institutions are complementary when the existence of one raises the efficiency of a second institution. (Amable 2000, Aoki 2001, Aoki 1994, Hall and Soskice 2001, Höpner2005). A related interpretation is that one institution within a domain A can only function efficiently, when a second institution is present in domain B. The mathematical foundation is based on the notion of super-modularity, which essentially means that elements are linked in discrete structures.

An encompassing framework within this line of work is provided by the Varieties of Capitalism (VoC) literature (Hall and Soskice 2001, Estevez-Abe et al.2001). It takes a firm-centered view of the economy by analyzing the predominant coordinating device used by firms. In liberal market economies (LME) firms rely predominantly on the use of markets, hierarchies and arm’s length contracting. In coordinated market economies (CME) there are additional non-market institutions, which facilitate coordination among companies. Table 1 provides a stylized overview of the predominant institutions in CMEs and LMEs.

As already postulated by North (1990), the institutional environment provides incentives, in what kind of skills and knowledge to invest. While North is primarily concerned with the development of economies and hence lays great emphasis on the distinction of “good” vs. “bad” institutions, here the focus is on the type of investment decisions facilitated by the institutional environment. For Hall and Soskice this is connected to the specificity of investments and accompanying innovation strategies. In short, it is argued that in CMEs the institutional environment gives incentives to invest in highly specific assets, both for employees and for firms. On the contrary, in LMEs individuals will invest comparatively more in general assets, which can be put to use in a broad range of activities without losing value. The institutional settings in the sub-system of corporate governance and social security can serve as an example: in a CME the high protection of both employment and unemployment of workers gives incentives to invest in specific human capital on the part of the workers.

Table 1

CME

LME

Financial System

Bank-based

Capital market

Corporate Governance

Stakeholder

Shareholder

Industrial Relations

Country-, industry-level

Firm-level

Social Security

High protection, low flexibility

Low protection, high flexibility

Vocational training

Specific human capital

Generic human capital

Inter-firm relations

Cooperation

Competition

They expect that the appropriation of the quasi-rent of specific assets, i.e. being fired and having to accept a job with a different skill profile, is less likely than elsewhere. The management of the firm can furthermore commit itself to retaining the workforce during economic hardships, because the corporate governance system is built around the principle of ‘patient capital’. This means that banks and stakeholders secure credit through dense webs of cross-shareholding and other monitoring devices (Vitols2001, 2004). Hence, the company can pursue investment strategies, which rely on incremental product innovations, such as diversified quality production (Streeck 1991). Here, it can be seen that the focus is on outcomes of institutional complementarities: as a result of “fitting” institutions an innovation strategy of incremental innovation is feasible. For LMEs, the logic runs the other way: here employment and unemployment protection is not existent or low, hence employees will invest in portable, generic skills. They cannot be sure that investment in higher specificity of assets would pay off. For the management of firms in LMEs, it is of utmost importance to be able to present good performance measures to shareholders. Flexible labor laws make it possible to ‘hire and fire’, which is one way of achieving good short-term profitability figures. Here, the resulting innovation strategies for firms are radical innovations. Liquid financial markets and hostile takeovers make it easy to move fast into new markets and change innovation strategies quickly. Also, as stated above, fluid labor markets foster radical shifts of companies into new business fields. Hence, institutional complementarities both constrain and enable actors to engage in particular activities.

To sum up the basic rationale of VoC, the institutional environment in CMEs and LMEs facilitates different predominant types of assets in both systems. These, in turn, go together with different innovation strategies. Apart from Germany as the prime example other European and Asian countries are considered a coordinated market economy, while the Anglo-Saxon countries form the group of liberal market economies.

Table 2

Coordinated Market Economies

Liberal Market Economies

Mixed Market Economies

Germany

Netherlands

Belgium

Austria

Switzerland

Denmark

Finland

Sweden

Norway

United Kingdom

United States

Canada

New Zealand

Australia

Italy

France

Spain

Portugal

Greece

Apart from that, some countries are not placed in the CME camp, because they lack some decisive features of it. Greece, Spain, Portugal, Italy and also France are such ‘mixed market economies’ (Hall and Soskice 2001; Molina and Rhodes2007). See Table 2 for an overview. Some authors argue that it makes more sense to talk about liberal market economies and lump everything else into one ‘non-liberal’ group, whose defining feature is the stark contrast to countries, which predominantly rely on market relationships (cf. in Streeck and Yamamura2001).

Find Out How UKEssays.com Can Help You!

Our academic experts are ready and waiting to assist with any writing project you may have. From simple essay plans, through to full dissertations, you can guarantee we have a service perfectly matched to your needs.

View our services

Having defined sectoral innovation strategies and institutional differences between countries, it is argued that those innovation strategies give rise to comparative institutional advantages of nations, because different sectors rely more on one type of innovation than others. The support from institutional complementarities for certain activities as described above is different in LMEs from CMEs. It can be expected that this is reflected in the structure of the economy. Hall and Soskice (2001) submit the hypothesis that CMEs are relatively better at product strategies connected to incremental innovation, such as machine tools, consumer durables, engines and so on. LMEs, by contrast, are seen as relatively better in activities such as biotechnology, semiconductors, IT and so on. To provide evidence, Hall and Soskice provide patent data from the European Patent Office for patents from Germany and the US are used to calculate a specialization index. For the respective country, an industry is listed if that country specializes in the respective technology field. Specialization is given when the share of patents of a particular industry in total domestic patents is larger than the respective global share.

Table 3

CME (Germany

LME (USA)

Civil engineering

Consumer goods

Weapons

Nuclear engineering

Transport

Agricultural machines

Handling

Mechanical elements

Engines

Machine tools

Environment

Thermal processes

Material processing

Surfaces

Process engineering

Basic materials

Pharmaceuticals

Polymers

Control systems

Electrical energy

Surfaces

Basic materials

Agriculture, food

New materials

Biotechnology

Pharmaceuticals

Organic chemistry

Medical engineering

Control systems

Optics

Semiconductors

Information technology

Telecommunications

As can be seen from Table 3, Germany is specialized in the very areas, which are usually conferred to as incrementally advanced diversified quality production. On the other hand, American firms are relatively better in industries, which rely on radical innovations.

Taylor (2004)in a first step confirms Hall and Soskice’s (2001) classification of industries in either relying on incremental or radical innovation. Extending the analysis over a longer time span and a larger country set, however, he finds that the significance of results of clear comparative advantages between Germany and the USA exist hinges on the inclusion of the United States.

Apart from patents, trade data are also used to map comparative institutional advantage. Panuescu and Schneider (2004)use the share of high-tech and medium-tech technology sectors in total exports of a country as a dependent variable. The intuition is that LME countries will specialize more on high-tech industries with a large R&D-intensity, while CME countries specialize on medium-tech activities characterized by a lower R&D intensity. To correct for imports they include the relative advantage of both for a total of 20 countries. The results are overall supportive for the claim that LMEs specialize in industries dependent on high R&D expenditures and hence radical innovations, while the comparative advantage of CMEs of high relative to medium-tech categories is significantly lower than for LMEs (52-55). More rigorously, Allen et al. (2006) and Allen (2006)classify economic activities as being either based on specialized supplier relations or science-based industries. The former are associated with incremental innovation strategies, while the later rely on radical innovation. The authors find broad support for VoC’s claim of comparative advantages for all countries studied by the literature. Watson (2003) in turn, does not find support for trade flows following the pattern of institutional differences using a social-security index and a size-adjusted trade index of country pairs. Similarly, Beyer (2006) reports mixed results.

Carlin and Mayer (2003) undertake a related approach. They investigate empirically the relationship between institutions of the financial system (such as disclosure requirements), structural characteristics (such as ownership concentration), and sectoral growth and R&D investments. Sectors with a high dependence on equity and high skills grow stronger and display higher R&D expenditures with more information disclosure and higher ownership concentration. The results suggest that differences in corporate governance systems could provide comparative advantages for technologies, which require different kinds of funding and/or commitments.

2.2 Institutional arbitrage

The notion of comparative institutional advantages among nations has strong theoretical appeal. The empirical record with regard to quality differences of institutions appears to be strong, while evidence on the impact of types of institutions and systems differences are mixed. At the same time, international factor movements have increased since the 1980s with foreign direct investments playing an increasingly strong economic role. In the second half of the 1990s, FDI inflows worldwide grew annually by 40% on average. The worldwide inward stock of FDI is 23% of the World’s real GDP in 2005 (UNCTAD 2006).

Against this backdrop, the institutional arbitrage hypothesis expects investments to be shifted to those countries, where the institutional environment and corresponding comparative institutional advantage suits them best. As multinational corporations (MNCs) can now easier relocate production to other economies exploiting advantages in resource endowments, factor costs and market sizes, in addition VoC predicts that it is easier to utilize institutional differences across countries and accompanying comparative institutional advantages (Soskice 1999:118, Hall and Soskice2003:248, Hancké et al.2007). The opportunity of institutional arbitrage is also much emphasized by the strategic management literature, both in theoretical elaboration (Porter1990, 1996, Hoskisson et al. 2004) and strategic advice for companies to exploit institutional differences more consistently (Ghemawat 2003).

However, the extent of the opportunity for arbitrage crucially depends on the capacities of the local sectors. In order for the comparative advantage to play out fully, there has to be an “industrial tradition” of a sector (Resmini2000), which provides skilled labor and company networks. Ideally, sectoral data measuring for instance skill level or skill intensity would be desirable, but such data do not exist. But. a straightforward way to proxy the strength of a sector in that respect is to look at the value-added it produces. In general, a sector that produces a greater value-added can be expected to be of significant importance and therefore possess the institutional capacities needed to fully reap the benefits of a comparative institutional advantage. So, we will expect the institutional advantage to be most clearly visible in large and potent sectors rather than niche sectors. Econometrically, as will be explained in more detail below, this means introducing interaction terms between value-added and comparative advantage indices.

Accordingly, in order to test the proposition we will suppose that in addition to traditional determinants of foreign direct investment location such as distance, labor costs and market size, the institutional environment should play a decisive role in the investment decision. The next section introduces the empirical literature on the determinants of FDI.

2.2 Determinants of foreign direct investment

FDI activities can be categorized as horizontal and vertical FDI. Horizontal FDI refers to a situation when a horizontal stage of the production process is duplicated in a foreign country. Vertical FDI, in contrast, occurs when the production process is split up and a part of the production chain is entirely relocated.

In both cases, trade-offs arise, which a firm contemplating any of the two types of foreign direct investment must resolve. For horizontal investments the firm loses economies of scale on the plant level, because the singular plants become smaller. However, the firm gains better market access. In the second case of vertical foreign direct investment costs of disintegration arise through the split of the production chain. On the other hand, differences of relative factor supplies, hence cheaper factor costs in the host country, are the potential gain for this kind of investment. Form the considerations in the previous section it follows that not only differences in factor endowments but also institutional differences can be seen as determinants of (vertical) FDI. Both views can also be treated simultaneously in a unified model, in which horizontal and vertical FDI are considered special cases (Markusenand Maskus 2002).

Both theoretical and empirical problems arise when trying to disentangle country determinants for horizontal vs. vertical FDI. On the one hand exact classification of the type of investment poses problems, since the distinction is not always clear-cut. Then, theoretical predictions of the effects of country traits on either type of investment are unclear. Higher trade costs should encourage horizontal FDI while it should discourage vertical FDI. Larger markets of the host country will most certainly lead to higher horizontal investment, but it can also be shown for vertical FDI (Zhang and Markusen1999). Cheaper factor costs encourage vertical investments, but no predictions can be made for horizontal.

Apart from that it is very difficult to distinguish between horizontal and vertical types of FDI from the data. One would need to have detailed data on the destination of sales of host country affiliates, whether they are within the host country, are directed to the home country or to a third country. Since such data are not available as in our case, we concentrate on the traditional way to model country determinants using gravity equations. In general, gravity equations attempt to explain the distribution of FDI across countries mainly by factors such as distance, GDP and factor costs (see overview in Barba Narvaretti and Venables2004, chapter 6). In such a setting, researchers have to live with the fact that their data include both horizontal and vertical FDI. Traditionally, gravity models were utilized to explain trade flows and volumes; the first application to investments flows is from Eeaton and Tamura(1994).

While in trade theory a recent literature attempts to model institutional diversity of countries and accompanying comparative institutional advantages in order to explain discrepancy between theory and empirics of the traditional trade models (see section 2.1), to our knowledge this has not been done yet in the FDI literature. Studies, which take into account institutions of the host country focus on FDI flows from advanced countries to developing and transition countries (Garibaldi et al.2002, Kinoshita and Campos2003, Wei2000, Du et al. 2008). In contrast, Habib and Zurawicki(2002) and BŽnassy-QuŽrŽ et al.(2007) have a broader scope by including also bilateral flows between advanced market economies. What these studies have in common is that they focus on the quality of institutions by including World Bank governance indicators or by measuring an institutional distance of quality and do not explicitly focus on comparative advantages. As explained above, our focus is on differences of institutional types exemplified by distinctive institutional systems sewn together by institutional complementarities.

3. Methodology

We estimate the amount of German FDI as a function of a vector of explanatory variables including both country and sector characteristics. We estimate the size of German (log) FDI stocks to sector i of country j as a function of country and sector characteristics. We postulate that FDI should tend to flow to sectors enjoying a comparative advantage in the host country. The VoC-Dummy is constructed such that it takes the value 1 if the sector has a postulated comparative advantage, and 0 if not:

Table 4 shows which economic activity of the FDI classification (according to ISIC Rev. 3) we classified as either being favored by a CME and an LME, respectively. The classification follows Allen et al.’s (2006) distinction between radical innovation sectors and incremental innovation sectors and it is in line with Hall and Soskice’s (2001) results given in Table 3 for Germany and the USA.

The estimation equation then is:

As stated above, it is expected that the comparative institutional advantage should be strongest in large sectors. In order to capture that effect, VoC and value-added are introduced as interaction terms. The coefficient on value-added is assumed to be positive, since a larger sector should attract more FDI. Also, VoC is expected to enter with a positive sign.

There are two ways to interpret the interaction effect. We expect that ceteris paribus a larger sector will receive more FDI if the sector enjoys a comparative advantage. A second way to state the same thing is to expect that the size of the sector is only relevant if the advantage is actually present. As a result, we will have to interpret the marginal effects if the conditioning effect when the comparative advantage is present (V

 

Cite This Work

To export a reference to this article please select a referencing stye below:

Reference Copied to Clipboard.
Reference Copied to Clipboard.
Reference Copied to Clipboard.
Reference Copied to Clipboard.
Reference Copied to Clipboard.
Reference Copied to Clipboard.
Reference Copied to Clipboard.

Related Services

View all

DMCA / Removal Request

If you are the original writer of this essay and no longer wish to have your work published on UKEssays.com then please: